Reappraising Self-Regulation Part III:
Is it time to replace Wall Street’s "self-regulation" with
"private sector regulation?"
By Bill Singer
Published in 2002
e-mail: bsinger@rrbdlaw.com
http://www.securitiesindustrycommentator.com
A Dangerous Chameleon
In the two prior parts of this article we examined how
self-regulatory organizations ("SROs") enjoy a chameleon-like existence; at
times being deemed governmental in nature; at other times, being deemed a
private entity; and, at other times, being deemed quasi-governmental. Such
transmutation immunizes the SROs against lawsuits by the investing public and
the securities industry, while denuding industry participants under
investigation of constitutional and due process protections (most notably the
Fifth Amendment right against self incrimination). Similarly, this sophisticated
game of hide-and-seek frequently blurs the boundaries between civil and criminal
enforcement of the securities laws and opens the door (or already widens the
portal) to facile cooperation between, on the one hand, government prosecutors
bound by strict grand jury secrecy and subject to due process requirements, and,
on the other hand, SROs who deem themselves unfettered by the restraints of
their governmental colleagues.
Punitive Agendas
The strength of self-regulation is that it is often the
quickest way to curtail serious securities industry misconduct. However, the
cost of such aggressive prosecution is, at times, too dear, as was divulged in
unsavory detail by the United States Department of Justice (Antitrust Division)
and the Securities and Exchange Commission during their 1996 investigations of
the NASDAQ stock market. In more recent times, we learn of other examples of
improper regulatory conduct as alleged by the Department of Justice and the SEC
in their investigations of the Oakford scandal at the New York Stock
Exchange.
The SROs are inextricably tied to the stock markets they
regulate and when promulgating and enforcing market regulations, those same
organizations are routinely confronted with circumstances where one membership
segment is advantaged when another is disadvantaged, or the public’s interests
are furthered at the expense of the industry. This dynamic remains at the heart
of all self-regulation. Can the regulator remain impartial? Can the regulator
transcend its own parochial interests? How does a regulator fairly regulate a
stock market so that public investors, industry member firms, industry
employees, and public issuers are all protected? The New Testament warns
that no man can serve two masters, how then can an SRO serve four?
SROs must never become partisan combatants. They must remain,
at heart, referees consistently and impartially applying the rules. In the clash
of ideas in the marketplace, misplaced SRO paternalism reduces innovation,
inbreeds inefficiencies, and artificially limits free-market competition.
Ultimately, the SROs’ mission is not amenable to any degree of compromise that
affords lesser/greater protection to one of the four market participants at the
expense of the others.
Re-defining the Self in Self-Regulation
But what is the definition of the term "self" in
self-regulation? Who its scope?" What constituencies are covered? At present,
Congress and the SEC seem content to permit the SROs to define the term "self"
as effectively limited to their member firms. Essentially, Wall Street is viewed
as a business of member firms. And what precisely is a member firm? It is
management/employer. Who then at the SROs speaks on behalf of labor/employee? A
member firm frequently enables private companies to go public and provides for
an aftermarket for such securities. Who then at the SROs speaks on behalf of the
issuers? A member firm often recommends/trades securities with public investors.
Who then at the SROs speaks on behalf of the public investor? Finally, member
firms are not monolithic but vary among many fault lines: retail, institutional,
regional, national, full-service, discount. Who then at the SROs speaks on
behalf of each interest group?
As recent history has all too clearly demonstrated, SROs tend
to favor their larger members over their smaller. Certainly, to the extent that
regulatory agendas have become politicized as a result of special interest group
lobbying, the bias has always been in the direction of the members providing
more revenue to the SRO. Consequently, smaller interest groups (frequently
so-called mavericks and bothersome innovators) tend to find themselves on the
defensive --- unwelcome, subjected to added scrutiny, denied representation on
committees and subcommittees. Similarly, the hundreds of thousands of registered
individuals (who are not technically "members" of any SRO --- such distinction
only permitted to an entity) are routinely subjected to regulation pursuant to
rules on which they are denied a vote and are called before hearing panels whose
members they cannot nominate nor elect. And keep in mind that many
disciplinary/arbitration proceedings often divide along an employer/employee
line in which management has adopted certain policies not necessarily favorable
to labor’s concerns. Accordingly, it goes without saying that if the "self" in
SROs is the member firm, that there are similar built-in conflicts with the best
interests of issuers and public customers.
The simplest way to distill the nature of this debate is to
merely look at the title of the NASD --- the National Association of Securities
Dealers, Inc. Historically, NASD was an association of dealers --- The
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 defines a "dealer" as any person "engaged in the
business of buying and selling securities for such person’s own account through
a broker or otherwise." However, Wall Street is far larger than those who
function as securities dealers. Further, since for many broker-dealers and
registered persons membership/registration with NASD is mandatory --- the
so-called "only game in town." The culture they join does not always welcome
them with open arms. One need only look back in recent time to recall the
hostility of the old-guard dealers to discount commissions, online trading,
decimalization, day trading and direct access platforms. While some of this
antagonism is certainly understandable as protectionism of traditional "dealer"
interests, it also served to set the stage for the NASD’s subsequent
difficulties with the Department of Justice and SEC. In a sense, it is time for
the NASD to shed its role as a regulator of the dealer community and for it to
move on to the next stage in its evolution. The NASD’s culture needs to change
to a more inclusive one.
The once quaint view that the Wall Street is a famous street
with a graveyard at one end and a river at the other is simply outdated. The
Stock Market’s gyrations no longer send rumbles to the blocks adjoining Wall
Street, but now set off convulsions and aftershocks throughout America and the
world. Wall Street has become so much more than a mere local business; it is the
heartbeat of the world’s capitalist system. Clearly, the "self" in
self-regulation is not a provincial issue to be left to a few powerful member
firms.
The Pitt Manifesto: Change Self to Private
In the midst of the unfolding Enron scandal, SEC
Chairman Harvey Pitt recently conceded that there was much public debate
concerning "whether there should be private regulation of the accounting
profession with vigorous SEC oversight or direct SEC regulation." In considering
the merits of the proposition, Pitt expressed his strong belief that
[P]rivate regulation presents major advantages, both
in quality control and discipline. It allows quality control that is
more flexible, but also more effective. The SEC is best suited to bring
actions for civil violations of law - fraud and such. Private regulation
can govern conduct that may not be unlawful, but reflects ethical lapses
and deficiencies in competence. And that discipline can be applied more
quickly and therefore more effectively. . . .
Chairman Pitt further opined that direct government
regulation of the accounting profession would likely not work and the cost of
government involvement in the audit and oversight processes could prove
prohibitive. He concluded that the accounting profession could be best regulated
by the private sector, subject to SEC oversight, with the costs spread among all
effected private parties.
All in all, a well-reasoned analysis, but one that
subsequently took an odd turn. Where one would have anticipated that Chairman
Pitt would ultimately urge adoption of the securities industry’s self-regulatory
model, he states that
The SEC has had a successful history with two-tier
regulation that involves the private sector. Such two-tier regulation
has been largely successful with the brokerage industry. SEC oversight
has been strengthened over the years to make that process more
effective, and I have proposed the strongest possible oversight of
private sector accounting regulation. Let me also emphasize that this
would be "private sector" but not "self" regulation. Self-regulation
implies that the accounting profession would regulate itself. We are
suggesting, without always being clearly heard, regulation by the
private sector but not by the profession.
Chairman Pitt raises an interesting distinction between
"self" regulation and "private sector" regulation. Self-regulation in his
lexicon apparently means exactly that --- a given industry/profession regulates
itself. Private sector regulation as he uses the term, seems to have a
very different meaning: one where all those mutually benefiting from ethical
conduct of a profession undertake the task of regulation and share the cost. In
Chairman Pitt’s worldview the accounting profession ought not regulate itself;
rather, it should be a partner in the process with other private sector
participants.
As I see it, the best way to ensure more ethical and
effective self- regulation is to adopt Chairman Pitt’s perspective of private
sector regulation. Ultimately, Wall Street ought not be a game preserve for a
few major broker-dealers. It’s time to set a larger table. The SROs need to
transform themselves beyond the regulation of Wall Street by Wall Street. It’s
time that the entire private sector stepped in: member firms, registered person,
issuers, and public customers. And it’s also time that the costs of such
regulation were apportioned fairly among those who will share in the benefits.
THE COST OF SELF REGULATION
On January 15, 2002, the NASD posted a Special Notice to
Members 02-09, seeking comment on changing the NASD’s regulatory transaction
fee.—The NTM candidly concedes that
NASD currently assesses its members a regulatory fee
on all transactions reportable through the Automated Confirmation
Transaction service (ACT). NASD has not modified this fee structure
since 1983. Given the dynamic changes taking place in our industry, the
existing pricing structure is becoming outdated. Moreover, NASD needs to
modernize the structure of the regulatory fee to take into account
Nasdaq's separation from NASD and registration as a national securities
exchange.
Why the need to modernize fees? Perhaps the answer is found
in a recent NASD announcement that its Board of Directors had approved the sale
of its remaining 33.7 million shares of NASDAQ common stock to the NASDAQ Stock
Market. According to NASD Chairman and CEO Robert Glauber, this divestiture of
NASDAQ enables NASD to
concentrate solely on our self-regulatory mission of
bringing integrity to the markets and confidence to investors. And by
reinforcing our resources, independence and focus, today’s step will
help us regulate Nasdaq and a growing number of other markets more
effectively than ever. . ."
Can the NASD really be considered independent if it relies
upon transactional fees from NASDAQ and OTC transactions? Doesn’t such a revenue
stream to a self-regulator create irreconcilable conflicts of interest? How can
a regulator not be sensitive to any reduction in trading volume--- which must
obviously result in a decrease in revenues? And now that the NASD no longer owns
NASDAQ (but merely generates revenues from the transactions occurring in that
market), isn’t there even more pressure to regulate in a manner that ensures
higher levels of trading? And won’t that give larger members generating higher
transaction levels even more influence? It’s sort of the difference between not
earning revenue from the sale of cigarettes but, rather, from each puff.
Additionally, it would seem that NASD has only a few sources
of revenue: transaction fees, membership fees, and regulatory fines. Transaction
fees will likely prove resistant to arbitrary increases; in fact, in this
present economy with more competition for less business, one should expect to
see pressure to maintain (if not lower) existing fees. Similarly, these are
tough times and membership fees cannot be arbitrarily raised to close budget
gaps or fund new ventures.
The Speed Trap of Regulatory Fines
We seem left with the inescapable conclusion that
self-regulators may put their cross-hairs on regulatory fines as a way to
enhance revenues. Of course, the dirty little secret with such agendas is that
one frequently notices a discomforting increase in the number of
enforcement actions. During such blitzes the practice is to ticket for a whole
host of minor violations --- hoping for the quick payment to settle the
nuisance. Such a practice is all too reminiscent of a speed trap behind some
billboard on a quiet rural highway. The small town paying the motorcycle cop
loves to raise the costs of the ticket and the frequency of pulling over the
unsuspecting out-of-towner. And should you be foolish enough to demand a jury
trial, good luck with the panel of taxpayers whose assessments are kept low by
the revenues from the tickets.
Should regulators be in the "business" of collecting fines? I
continue to believe that one of the failures of Wall Street’s regulatory
community is that far too many defrauded public customers win
litigation/arbitration verdicts against disreputable firms and individuals, only
to be unable to collect their awards. Wall Street would certainly be taking the
moral high ground if it allocated all collected regulatory fines to a fund for
the exclusive benefit of defrauded public customers unable to collect their
awards. Similarly, by crediting collected fines to their operating accounts, the
SROs create a troublesome conflict by generating revenue through enforcement
activities. This only fuels the legitimate concern that SROs give higher
performance evaluations (and hence larger bonuses and better promotion
consideration) to regulatory employees who do a superb investigative job and
recommend an enforcement action, but somehow deem those employees who do not
recommend an enforcement action as not so entitled.
SROS AS ADVOCATES NOT PROXIES
SROs cannot act effectively when they lack first-hand
familiarity with the practices of Wall Street. There must be some sensitivity
for the professionals and the industry being regulated. Consequently, it is
critical that an appropriate number of regulators have actually worked on the
Street. If SROs merely hire from the ranks of the SEC and state prosecutors, one
must ask whether the system is nothing more than a redundancy rubber-stamping
governmental agendas. Accordingly, SROs must be more than a dummy in an SEC or
NASAA ventriloquist act. Wall Street should not be saddled with self-regulators
who only parrot the SEC or unquestioningly bow in deference to the states. For
self-regulation to properly function, its regulators must be prepared to
advocate the industry’s best interests when appropriate. This means that
those involved in self-regulation must reaffirm each SRO’s proper role as a
full-fledged partner in the regulatory process, and not merely as a proxy for
the SEC or states.
Going Forward
The markets will become publicly owned and the dominance of the NASD and NYSE
are daily being challenged by expanding alternative trading systems and growing
international competition. The public markets’ success will not be determined by
the NASDAQ or NYSE composite index, which measures the profitability of the
listed companies. To the contrary, after demutualization, success will be
determined by the profitability of the market itself. And woe be it if the
NASDAQ or NYSE cannot turn a profit or begins losing market share to some
upstart. One only needs to look as far as NASDAQ’s most recent 10-Q for the
period ended September 30, 2001 (http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1120193/000095017201501137/0000950172-01-501137.txt)
to see what the future may hold:
Nasdaq reported net income of $53.7 million for the nine months ended
September 30, 2001, compared to net income of $12.6 million for the nine
months ended September 30, 2000. Compared to pro forma net income for
the nine months ended September 30, 2000 of $113.7 million, excluding
the cumulative effect of the change in accounting principle, net income
decreased by $60.0 million, or 52.7%.
Daily share volume is down. All primary revenue streams are suffering.
Transaction services revenues are declining. Perhaps more ominously, in addition
to the general economic downturn, NASDAQ’s market information services and
transaction services revenues face a competitive threat from other stock
exchanges that trade its listed stocks and there is certainly a potential for
significant erosion NASDAQ’s market share of trading activity and the related
market information services and transaction services revenues as new exchanges
arise or existing exchanges increase their market share.
Conclusion: We Need A National SRO
It is time for us to put to rest the concept of "self" regulation and move
forward with the more dynamic alternative of "private sector" regulation. SRO
boards must be opened up to wider representation from the private sector. Board
seats should be allocated for the President of the Public Investors’ Arbitration
Bar Association (or another similarly credible investors’ organization) and for
a representative of the more than half-million registered persons in the
industry. Individual registered persons must be enfranchised and permitted to
vote on the rule proposals relating to their profession. And of course, it’s
high time that we provide industry employees and member firms with a bill of
rights regarding the conduct of SRO investigations.
SRO management must find more creative ways to finance their operations and
any resort to fines as stopgap financing must be abandoned. It is simply
unacceptable that the critical job of privately policing Wall Street should be
handled by individuals whose best hopes of compensation is not comparable to
their industry counterparts. Private regulation is not supposed to be amateur
hour; nor, should the rolls of SRO employees be filled with rejects from the
private and public sector. Similarly, there must be a financial commitment to
maintain a veteran complement of regulators and to stop the damaging revolving
door. True, in these difficult times SROs will find it easier to hire and retain
experienced staff --- but this recession will not last forever and good times
will once again deplete the ranks of skilled regulators. Consequently, I call
for the creation of a salary/bonus system for regulatory employees that is more
competitive with the compensation structure of the same industry being
regulated. Similarly, longevity should not entitle any regulator to promotion.
We already have enough SRO managers who are not up to the task but simply obtain
promotions by staying on the job long after the Street hired their more
qualified colleagues. Ultimately, Wall Street is better served when regulated by
well-compensated professionals.
Finally, I believe that the time has now come to merge all the existing SROs
into one, national SRO. The funding for that organization should be derived from
a fee on each securities transaction in the markets, from a fee on each public
offering, and from reasonable membership/registration fees. By developing such a
pool of funding, the national SRO will be largely freed from conflicts caused by
reliance upon the one market each present SRO regulates. All regulatory fines
should be deposited into a fund to be administered for the purpose of
compensating defrauded public investors who can demonstrate an inability to
collect awards rendered against member firms and registered persons.
[a version of this article previously appeared in eSecurities
(Vol.4, No.6 Feb.2002)
|